In this series, we have used the recent announcement by CVS Health regarding a strategy to lower drug prices as an example to review basic pharmacoeconomic principles. For Part 3, we are going to discuss various stakeholders and how each might view the results of decisions based off of pharmacoeconomic analyses.
In this series, we have used the recent announcement by CVS Health regarding a strategy to lower drug prices as an example to review basic pharmacoeconomic principles. In Part 1, we focused on the incremental cost-effectiveness ratio (ICER) and a scenario using quality-adjusted life-years (QALYs) as the primary measure for effectiveness. In Part 2, we began to place the resulting ICER into context so it could be applied to making a decision recommendation. For Part 3, we are going to discuss various stakeholders and how each might view the results of decisions based off of pharmacoeconomic analyses.
Who are the stakeholders?
When it comes to making “managed care” decisions involving the treatment of one’s health, it is important that we consider several potential stakeholders:
Now that we have identified a set of stakeholders, let’s walk through a few scenarios and discuss how each may be impacted.
Scenario A: Brand new (expensive and effective) drug is covered because it is cost-effective compared to the current standard of care for a subset of patients in our population (determined by our cost/QALY calculation <$100,000/QALY).
For the individual patients & caregivers impacted directly by the new treatment, the determination to include on the formulary means increased access to the therapy, as many patients may not be able to afford the treatment without the support of a third party payer. The benefits may include decreases in mortality or morbidity (remember that using the QALY incorporates both the length of life and the quality of life).
For the clinicians, inclusion on the formulary will hopefully make day-to-day operations a bit easier as their staff will be able to spend less time worried about patient access. If the formulary decision incorporates several managed care hurdles (step-therapy, prior authorization, etc.), then the clinicians may bear a bit more of the burden in terms of ensuring their patients have access to the new treatment.
For the payer, the decision to cover based on a <$100,000/QALY calculation only explains efficiency of the new treatment versus the old treatment. It says nothing about the impact on the overall budget for the health plan. In other words, the payer must estimate how much more the entity will spend on the new treatment compared to previous years and will need to make adjustments to ensure they have the funds. This could be done in a few ways. First, the payer could eliminate payment for other services in the plan (which would impact other patients, clinicians, etc.). Second, the payer could increase the overall contributions or premium amounts necessary to make up for the new spending. This means employers, taxpayers, or other covered individuals in the plan will be expected to pay more to ensure a subset of patients get access to the new treatment.
For the pharmaceutical manufacturer, formulary inclusion means access to a larger pool of customers and increased sales of product. This may not necessarily reflect greater profitability, as a large insurance company may require overall price concessions (through rebates or discounts) from the manufacturer.
For society, gains may be realized through the improvement of health (as measured in total QALYs gained) in the population. Society may also benefit as healthier people may be more likely to contribute to the economy (ie: working, paying taxes, consuming goods).
Scenario B: Brand new (expensive and effective) drug is NOT covered because it is not cost-effective compared to the current standard of care for a subset of patients in our population (determined by our cost/QALY calculation >$100,000/QALY).
For patients & caregivers, this negative coverage decision will ultimately limit the access to the treatment. Maybe a few patients will gain access through charitable networks or they may pay 100% out-of-pocket if they have the means to do so (which may create an equity issue). From the patient perspective, being denied a new treatment that is efficacious but not cost-effective could be incredibly disheartening as they see are denied health gains because it “costs too much.” This may be compounded by the numerous ads on television of smiling actors over-selling the effects, but we can save that issue for another post.
For the clinicians, this coverage decision can be extremely frustrating. From a clinical viewpoint, the gains in efficacy in the clinical trials are exciting (I mean, who settles for “good” when you can have “even better”?). In this case, the clinicians may share a patient-centric viewpoint and just want to find a way to get increased access. Many clinicians are amazing patient advocates who will gladly jump through administrative hurdles to get the drug to the patient.
For the payer, this is an extremely tough decision politically. Theoretically, by denying the treatment they are allocating the health plan’s dollars more efficiently (*DISCLAIMER* This assumes that everything else currently on the formulary is held to the same cost/QALY standard, which is likely not the case). Denying the treatment will certainly create a very unhappy subset of patients who may become vocal and slam the payer from a customer service perspective. In the case of the for-profit insurance market, customer service could potentially hurt future business. In the case of the government, denials could result in advocacy to our elected representatives.
For the pharmaceutical manufacturer, this certainly limits the revenue potential for the new therapy. The manufacturer could conduct more research to demonstrate greater clinical effectiveness or simply lower the price (also another topic that deserves its own post).
For society, whether or not there is a net benefit or loss with this decision may be unknown. If the cost/QALY calculation was only determined using a “health sector” perspective, then there is a chance the negative coverage decision will actually hurt society.
The Balancing Act
Moving to a system where formulary decisions made by a large health plan or pharmacy benefits manager incorporate economic analyses in a formal way will certainly create some controversy. Especially in Scenario B after a drug is approved, shown to be clinically effective, and fails to meet the cost-effectiveness threshold. When we step back and view a health plan as a large group of people, rather than individuals, it really is just a mathematical calculation (Which this series was meant to simplify for a broad audience).
Philosophically, many people support the idea of balancing the potential clinical gains with the additional costs to achieve those gains…until they are the one sick and hoping to receive the best treatment money can buy. We can all relate to the patient & caregiver group, as we have likely all experienced a situation where we faced a diagnosis with a poor prognosis if left untreated (either for ourselves or close relative). In future posts, I would like to discuss a few more nuances that might challenge our understanding and interpretation of a pharmacoeconomic analysis. Stay tuned!
Health Equity & Access Weekly Roundup: November 23, 2024
November 23rd 2024Americans are underinsured, even with employer-based health plans; a thorough critique of the lack of representation among Black patients in clinical trials showcases a persistent theme; systemic barriers in cardiology, breast cancer, and patent systems are examined.
Read More
FDA Accepts Resubmitted NDA for Ataluren in Nonsense Duchenne Muscular Dystrophy
November 22nd 2024The new drug application (NDA) includes data from a global placebo-controlled, 72-week study as well as findings from the STRIDE registry, an ongoing, observational, real-world study of ataluren in routine care.
Read More